The Illusion of Choice ?

Choice is the buzzword of everyone these days. We like choice. Choice is fundamental to capitalism. Every day we make decisions on an enormous number of things. In fact, we take choice so much for granted that we don’t even think about it when we make that “decision” between a Mars and a Snickers. Either way, it lines someone’s pocket somewhere.

So, then, it would not be alien to us to make choices in areas where choice is taboo. The public sector for instance. Starting with schools, then hospitals and ultimately which ambulance you’d prefer to be driven in because it has a lower accident rate and higher quality speed drivers.

The question is, do we really want that choice? And if so, will it achieve anything?

The government likes to claim that choice will help drive up standards. That’s a questionable assumption in the first place, but let’s run with it.

The public sector is not really a place where choice is compatible. We want things done as best we can, and as quickly as we can. Both of these may or may not involve too much of a consideration on cost, whereas the private sector ethos places great importance on the bottom line. An immediate incompatibility.

Say you are a parent. You have a choice of School A or School B for your 11-year-old child. School A is local, but not too good. School B is 10 miles away, but it is very good. You want to get your child into School B, and you, by some miracle, manage to achieve it. In the meantime, many other parents fail, and are forced into School A. Good schools for the few, not the many.

But let’s assume that Labour is right. The choice ethic makes School A work harder. School A sacks its headmaster, and drafts in a whole new management team. Over 5 years, they turn the school around. School A’s grades (which, incidentally, are measured by a school grading system no one trusts, but everyone hails the God Of League Tables anyway) improve enough that they are now on a par with School B.

The system is then equalled out. Choice has “driven up standards”.

But then what happens to choice? If School A and School B are the same now, why does it matter any more which one you choose? Why not go back to School A because it’s closer?

In this manner, why have choice in the first place? The theory is wonderful (there is no guarantee that School A would turn itself around: the problems may be sociological which the school cannot control), but in the end, the public sector has produced two largely undifferentiated institutions, both equally good. Choice is no longer necessary. The short-term choice has eliminated choice in the long term.

Contrast with the private sector. Marketing speaks of the 4 P’s: Product, Price, Place and Promotion. That decision between Mars and Snickers is on product: nutty Snickers or smooth Mars? How about a decision between Tesco and ASDA? Price virtually the same. Virtually the same range of products on offer. No difference in place. But promotion? Ahh – some differentiation is finally achieved: a psychological distinction between whether you prefer the fact that “every little helps” or you enjoy tinkling the back pocket to hear that satisfying jingle of loose change.

In short, private sector choice works because there is so much that you can differentiate on.

But in the public sector… if choice equalises standards, then choice is no longer needed. If the argument then were stretched to say public schools should compete for students on more than just chances of success and general school atmosphere, then I would argue that we are entering dangerous territory. If the product is the same and the price is the same, only place and promotion are left. I don’t want schools advertising for pupils by creating “brand images”; this only prays on a mentality I don’t want to see in education. This leaves only place… and suddenly we come back to where we started.

In an ideal world, most people would prefer the local school and hospital to be top notch. No one, in these circumstances, really wants to make a choice between which school and hospital you should go to. They could, should and can all be good. If Labour’s argument that choice will achieve that is borne out, then choice will eliminate itself from the equation, and we’ll be back to square one – you go to the local school or hospital because they are just that: local.

This is a vast oversimplification of the concept – there are hundreds of factors at play in society that are at the heart of the public sector reform issue that do not figure in discussions about private sector success – but it is the key principle upon which Labour’s reforms are being built. I believe choice may have some role to play initially, but it is neither the end, nor the means to achieve it. It is simply a part of a much wider solution to improving the public services: one which involves considering everything from society in turn, and not one which assumes that a private sector ethos will work wonders in an area where its ideas are largely incompatible.

6 comments
  1. You’re assuming that the quality of a school is measurable by a single variable, which can be compared against other schools in a total ordering, and that variable has the same value for all observers. I don’t think either of those are true.

    Different children learn in different ways, and benefit from different environments and curricula. Not all of those can be provided in the same school. Therefore, in order for education to better fit the child there must be a variety on offer into which he or she can fit.

    Also, the reason why choice works so well in the private sector is that it punishes failing institutions. Sometimes when an institution – school or company – fails, it is the fault of the directors. Sometimes it’s the fault of (some of) the employees. A few bad apples can wreck the working environment of a large number of people. And sometimes, in the most difficult to detect case, it is the fault of the institutional culture, the encrustation of tradition, politics, morale and policy which builds up anywhere and can support or strangle any effort. It’s much easier to disband a broken institution than it is to fix its culture.

  2. Eddie said:

    I assumed this for the sake of the argument. I don’t believe you can measure schools in variables, hence my quip about the God of League Tables.

    However, I feel this is the attitude the Labour government is cultivating. I took their ideas and ran with it.

  3. But what happens when school (or hospital or whatever) B is full?
    ‘Choice’ only benefits those with the nous to get in first, the sharpest elbows, the friends in the right places, the right post code, the loudest voice, the same club or dress-sense and so on.

    All those left will have to rely on school (hospital etc) A – until such a time as the fairy godmother of no-longer-failing waves her magic wand and sprinkles her fairy dust over it.

    Which, in essence, means the middle-class – who know how to work the system will get what they want, while those left behind will be the ones who could probably benefit the most, but lack the know-how or connections to exploit the system – the underclass in other words.

  4. EU Serf said:

    ……..Which, in essence, means the middle-class…..

    It would mean the same outcome then without a massive distortion in the price of houses close to good schools.

    The idea that choice will somehow cease to be an issue once School A catches up with School B is an interesting idea. In a world with one variable and where things stand still maybe.

    On the other hand, to bring in real choice, tax payers cash must be available for use in non state schools.

  5. Jarndyce said:

    Overall, Eddie, I think you’re simplifying the way markets work far too much. After all, if TV were solely state-run, we’d never have got Sky+…

    _…the price of houses close to good schools_

    … is probably the best argument in favour of education vouchers: that in effect we have markets at work already, just hidden in everything from house prices to the cost of a can of Coke in nice areas around good schools. And they would have one other advantage: I could make damn sure that the religious school round the corner from me, who in their Christian charity exclude my unbaptised daughter from attending, wouldn’t see one penny of “my” tax money.

    Overall, though, I think we should be very careful before chucking the notion of a shared civic education in the dustbin. The current system is crap – possibly in its shittyNuLabmiddlewayness the worst system of all – but marketizing would cause further atomization (medrassas in Marylebone, anyone?).

  6. Andrew said:

    In an ideal world, most people would prefer the local school and hospital to be top notch. No one, in these circumstances, really wants to make a choice between which school and hospital you should go to. They could, should and can all be good.

    This strikes me as wishful thinking. You describe an ideal world where all local public services would be equally excellent, so that choice would be unnecessary, and then jump to an assertion that this world is achievable. A simple question for you, then:

    How?

    Because decades of political meddling would seem to suggest that it isn’t really achievable…

    The brutal truth about public services is that there is a limit to that which we as society are prepared to fund and make available collectively (the ‘I don’t want to pay for other people’s Viagra/IVF/cosmetic surgery/Kumon Maths’ argument). This necessarily ends up restricting what you can do without implementing some element of choice and competition into the system. There will always be differentiating factors between services, because there will always be variability. It might be so small as the fact that one hospital is a slightly newer building, and just ‘feels healthier’ for that reason, but that’s choice.

    What the public really wants (collectively) is local services that are just adequate, not good. And broadly, that’s what we get.